Conceptual frameworks of accounting from an information perspective

Accounting and Busine,<:s Research, Vol. 40. No. 3 2010 International Accounting Policy Forum, pp. 287-299 287
Conceptual frameworks of accounting from
an information perspective
John Christensen
Abstract — This paper analyses the benefits of accounting regulation and a conceptual framework using an information
economics approach that allows consideration of uncertainty, multiple agents, demand for information, and multiple
infonnation sources. It also allows private infonnation to enter the analysis. The analysis leads to a set of fundamental
properties of accounting information. It is argued that the set of qualitative characteristics typically contained in conceptual
frameworks does not adequately aggregate the infonnation demands of users of accounting information. For example, the
IASB's conceptual fi^mework contains no guidelines for the trade-off between relevance and reliability. Furthermore,
neutrality might not be part of an optimal regulation. The statistical bias introduced by the stewardship use of accounting
information is not necessarily undesirable and will always remain; stewardship is the characteristic of accounting information
that provides incentives for management to act in the desired way. Accounting infonnation is inherently late compared to
other information sources but influences and constrains the content of more timely sources. The accounting system does not
exist in a vacuum. Other information sources are present and the purpose of the accounting system cannot be analysed
without considering the existence of other infonnation sources. Finally, financial statements are audited by an independent
auditor. This implies that accounting data are hard to manipulate.
Keywords: accounting regulation; conceptual fi^mework; qualitative characteristics; information economics
1. Introduction
The question I have been asked to address is how
conceptual frameworks contribute to the quality of
corporate reporting regulation. This is by no means
an easy task. In the paper I shall attempt to show that
an answer requires identification of the concept of
quality of corporate reporting, of the purpose of the
conceptual fi^amework, and of the benefits of
reporting regulation. In order to understand the
concept of the quality of corporate reporting it is
important to analyse the fiindamental characteristics
of accounting information and its limitations.
The idea of the conceptual fi-amework is to
provide a set of consistent principles to guide
regulation and reporting of financial information as
part of the political decision process. The IASB's
current conceptual fi-amework (IASC, 1989) gives
equal ranking to information that is usefiil to a wide
range of users in making economic decisions
(para. 12) and infonnation that shows the results
of stewardship of management (para. 14). The
Discussion Paper that sought to bring together the
IASB and FASB conceptual fi-ameworks (FASB/
IASB, 2006) asked whether stewardship had a
*The author is Professor of Accounting at the Department of
Business and Economics, University of Southern Denmark,
Campusvej 55, DK-5230 Odense M, Denmark. Tel: +45 6550
3244. E-mail: jcn@sam.sdu.dk.
He is grateful to the editor Pauline Weetman, an anonymous
referee, Paul Boyle, Robert Hodgkinson, Richard Macve,
Mogens Nielsen, Brian Singleton-Green, Alfi'ed Wagenhofer,
and the participants at the 2009 Information for Better Markets
Conference for helpful comments.
continuing role in the objective and indicated a
preference to focus solely on decision usefijlness
(para. BC1.32 to BC1.41). In the proposed conceptual
fi-amework (FASB/IASB, 2008) the main
objective of decision usefialness is expanded to
include information about 'management's ability to
protect and enhance the capital providers' investments'
(para. OB 9).
Previous work has shown that, in a single firm
setting, the accounting system has to be finely tuned
to the specifics of the organisation and its environment,
including the economics of the firm, the
decision problems at hand, the private information
of the-parties involved, the public information, and
the moral hazard problems of the organisation.
Furthermore, the world contains many firms and
many decision-makers.
It is impossible to construct an income measure
that reflects true income as defined by Hicks (1946)
when markets are not perfect and complete (Beaver
and Demski, 1979). Such a measure does not exist.
Rather, accounting should be viewed as an information
system as acknowledged by both FASB and
IASB in their original conceptual fi-ameworks
(;FASB, 1978; IASC, 1989). Unfortunately, there
is no universal ranking of information systems
(Christensen and Demski, 2003). In addition, it is
well known that no rational preference relation
describes the decision process of society (Arrow,
1951). The accounting system is the result of a
delicate balancing of the possibilities imbedded in
the accounting system and the demands of the users.
288 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
This balancing is not entirely of a technical nature as
it calls for balancing of preferences of the parties
involved. Such balancing cannot be achieved by
technical rule-making and is inevitably the result of
a political decision process.
The accounting income number reports firmspecific
financial information to the market and thus
reduces the information asymmetry in the market.
The paper considers how information is simultaneously
used by investors to make decisions and to
induce or infiuence management to behave optimally
or to use the entity's resources efficiently. The
decision-inñuencing role distorts the reporting
incentives. Once the accounting information is
used for performance evaluation (or for decisions
regarding replacement of management), incentives
for earnings management arise (Burgstahler and
Dichev, 1997; Graham et al., 2005). The reason is
that the financial statements include reporting of
private information by management as part of the
accruals. Auditing reduces this problem to some
extent. Managers often have an informational
advantage over the auditors and this prevents the
problem from being completely eliminated.
A current trend in financial reporting is toward
adoption of a fair value approach. It is highly
questionable whether this is a viable path. The firm
has an information advantage compared to the users
of financial information and this advantage is used
strategically in reporting. Fair value accounting
relies even more on the private information of
management, and enhances the possibilities for
earnings management and leaves auditing less
efficient. In addition, it is not obvious what
information should be included into the financial
statements. One question is whether the accounting
system or the users are better at performing the
aggregation of various information sources
(Christensen and Frimor, 2007).
A related question is how the accounting system
best complements other information sources. The
financial statements will always be published late
compared to other information sources. This is due
to the nature of financial statements as all transactions
must be processed and audited before the
statements are released. In contrast, management's
forecast might be timely. The prime purpose of
financial statements might be to provide incentives
for reporting of other types of information.
The conceptual frameworks of both IASB and
FASB identify sets of the qualitative characteristics
of financial information. The origin of the qualitative
characteristics is related to the decision orientation
of accounting and was stated in the ASOBAT
report on accounting theory (AAA, 1966). These
qualitative characteristics certainly describe the
attribute for a usefial information system when it is
used for decision-making purposes in a one-person
world. This might be very different in a multiperson
world. For example, one of the characteristics
calls for unbiased reporting standards, yet
recent research finds that the introduction of bias
might lead to welfare improvements (Christensen
and Demski, 2007). Furthermore, it is impossible to
maximise all qualitative characteristics simultaneously
and consequently there is a demand for
trade-offs. However, the frameworks are silent on
how to do this. In a multi-person world it is not
possible to replace the individual preferences with a
set of qualitative characteristics.
It is obvious that there is a demand for regulation
of financial reporting and that a conceptual framework
includes the objective and basic principles of
reporting regulation. Given the multi-person nature
of the problem it might take the form of a
constitution (in the sense of fiindamental laws and
principles). The benefit will be that the conceptual
framework forces the regulators to constantly seek
solutions that are maintaining and enhancing the
comparative advantage of the accounting system
compared to other information systems such as
press releases and web-based information sources.
An information economics framework allows
consideration of uncertainty, multiple agents,
demand for information, and multiple information
sources. It also allows asymmetry in the knowledge
of different stakeholders in the market such that the
firm knows something which is of value to the
market participants. Finally, it allows incentive
issues to be part of the analysis.
My analysis of how conceptual frameworks
contribute to the quality of corporate reporting
will fall into four parts. Section 2 will analyse the
supply of accounting information for decision and
control. Accounting accruals are seen as the primary
vehicle for management to report their private
information. The incentives for such reporting are
reviewed. Section 3 will deal with the demand for
financial information. It is argued that the demand
for decision purposes and control purposes leads
to different ranking of accounting systems. The
suggestion to have different accounting systems
for different purposes is analysed and rejected.
Section 4 will discuss the fundamental properties of
accounting information. The qualitative characteristics
and other fiandamental properties will be part
of this discussion. Section 5 will show the implications
of the analysis for the accounting regulation
and the conceptual framework. Conclusions are
offered in Section 6.
Vol. 40, No. 3. 2010 International Accounting Policy Fomm 289
2. The reporting organisation
2.1. Income measurement
One ofthe prime targets for accounting information
is the investor group and, according to common
wisdom, the main interest for this user group is the
future cash flows ofthe company. First assume that
the firm is placed in a perfect capital market under
certainty. The cash fiow series for the lifetime ofthe
firm is given by:
Given perfect capital markets, a no arbitrage
argument leads to the well-known result that the
A^PKof investing in a firm is zero. The value ofthe
firm at any given date t is given by:
PV,= >'-J
With this the ineome definition easily follows:
(2)
(3)
This is economic income and coincides with the
classical income as defined by Hicks (1946) and it is
equal to cash flow minus economic depreciation.
Again, a no arbitrage argument leads to this income
being equal to the interest eamed on the invested
capital or:
/, = iPV,-\ (4)
In a perfect world income measurement is not
interesting (Beaver and Demski, 1979). Everybody
knows everything and information adds nothing
new.
2.2. Decision information
Imperfection might take on many forms. The first to
be introduced here is adding some of the details
leading to the given cash flows. The firm is
producing one product and the basis for this is an
initial capital investment and labour in each period.
Both are acquired in perfect markets and the
production fiinction describes a feasible relationship
between inputs and output. The demand is
exogenously given for each period. The realised
cash flows are the consequence of optimal production
during the lifetime ofthe firm. If inventories are
possible and if the production fianction exhibits
economics of scale or scope, production smoothing
will be part of the optimal production schedule.
Thus, the total assets of the firm will both contain
the inventory of finished products and the fixed
assets. Despite the fact that the value of the firm is
uniquely determined, it is not possible to find
individual values ofthe two assets that add up to the
total value of the firm. The non-separability of the
cost function combined with the non-perfect markets
(for the finished product and the fixed assets)
leads to this result (Christensen and Demski, 2003).
The result points to the difficulty there is in defining
appropriate and descriptive accounting measures
even when faced with lots of regularity and
certainty. The analysis by Brom wich et al. (2009)
reinforces this point.
Now, no uncertainty leads to no demand for
information (or there is no such thing as information
in such a world). Formal introduction of uncertainty
into the model calls for a definition of the error
terms that have an influence on the cash flows in
each period. The simplest model of this type
includes the following stochastic cash flow series:
CF = [CFo + 60, CF, + E,,..., CFr + «r) (5)
Assume that the e,'s are identically and independently
distributed. The accounting system reports
routinely the realised cash flows, but the realised
cash flow ñ"om period j will have no predictive
ability with respect to fijture cash flows. Thus,
accounting information is only keeping track ofthe
realised cash flows, but it is hardly useful.
The introduction of a correlated error structure
changes this. Actions or decisions often have a
multi-period effect and this feeds into the stochastic
description of the fixture cash flows. Now observation/
reporting of the cash flows will provide
information that enables the user to update the
expectation ofthe future cash flows. This estimation
uses the correlation structure. This is information
for valuation purposes as in Peasnell (1982). For the
purpose of facilitating this estimation the accounting
system might be useful. This will be the case
when the accounting system, together with the
reporting of realised cash flows, provides more
insight into the error structure, thus enabling the
user to better form expectations about future cash
flows. More accounting variables might improve
the estimation. The key to finding valuable information
is to get information about the fiindamental
time processes or the components which characterise
the evolution ofthe cash flow series. Any bias in
the accounting variables does not matter as long as
the user is able to inverse the bias and decipher the
content of the accounts (Demski and Sappington,
1990). The important component remains the
unexpected error which is used to form expectations.
Any systematic bias in the accounting model
is easily countered through a balanced use of the
information.
Furthermore, the double entry accounting system
satisfying the clean surplus relations or the comprehensive
income contains counterbalancing
290 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
errors. Over the lifetime of the firm the accounting
income will always equal the total cash flows of the
firm. That is, whichever errors the present accounting
valuation includes, these are balanced by the
error in the ftiture expected accounting income
numbers (Feltham and Ohlson, 1995).
2.3. Control information
The control use of accounting numbers is often
modelled using the principal-agent model. The
principal hires an agent to perform a task for some
reason. The principal is unable to observe the action
selected by the agent and at the same time the act is a
source of disutility for the agent as he does not want
to work hard. The market for labour of the type of
the agent determines the level of the salary. The
agent has to be offered at least the utility he can get
from working elsewhere to accept working for the
principal. This is the classical moral hazard problem
(Hobnstrom, 1979). The naïve interpretation of this
model is cast in the form of a simple working
relationship. However, it is descriptive of much
more complex relationships. Managerial action
choices are hardly observable in a classic sense. In
the managerial context the issue of goal congruence
is also predominant in the management accounting
texts (Homgren et al., 2003; Antle and Demski,
1988). The bottom line is the agent (manager) wants
to select a different action from the one desired by
the principal (owner). This is the basic moral hazard
problem.
In response to this problem the owner introduces
an incentive scheme to make the manager select the
desired action. The infonnation supplied by the
accounting system becomes important here as the
payment is a ñinction of the available accounting
information and the additional contractible information
signal. The owner's outcome might or might
not be included in the accounting information. One
reason for this asymmetry is that the owner's time
horizon might extend beyond the accounting and
other information available. This is in line with the
net present value focus of the stockholders.
From an accounting perspective it is interesting
that the infonnation of value in this type of model is
infonnation about the act taken. That is, whenever
an additional infonnation source is available, it is
useftal or of value if it provides more information
about the act selected (Holmstrom, 1979). The
interesting infonnation in this context is information
that informs the parties about the source of the
market imperfection, in this case the non-observability
of the act selected. The ftandamental goal
conflict between the manager and the owner is
essential for this result. If that were not present, the
manager would simply choose the first best action.
Thus, the problem disappears when there is perfect
goal congruence in the organisation such that there
is no demand for incentive pay to promote the
actions desired by the owners. This includes the
tension between long-term and short-term profit
measures. Control problems are important to
accounting (Sunder, 1997).
The demand for infonnation for control purposes
is closely tied to the act selection. Thus, it depends
upon the set of available actions how these differ in
terms of the manager's preferences and in terms of
the owner's preferences. One information system is
preferred to another information system if it is better
at providing incentives for the manager to select the
desired action. Intuitively it translates into how the
infonnation systems are able to distinguish among
the available actions. When the focus is on the
accounting system it is also important to acknowledge
the presence of altemative infonnation
sources. The value of a particular accounting system
depends upon which other information sources are
present. This is, however, only part of the story.
2.4. Reporting incentives
Managers are employed to make decisions. They
are also supposed to collect and process information.
And finally, they are employed to report
infonnation, for example, through the accounting
system. Thus, part of the managerial job is to
acquire infonnation and this information is, unless
disclosed, private to the manager. Some managers
are even hired because they possess special knowledge,
which is also private infonnation. In all cases
this adds to the imperfection of the relationship
between the owner and the manager. Consequently,
the contractual arrangements between the two
become more complex in response to this private
infonnation. More interestingly, the timing of how
the events unfold becomes part of the problem.
If the private infonnation gets into the hands of
the manager after the actions have been selected,
there is no immediate control problem. The contract
that controlled the actions of the manager without
considering the new infonnation will continue to do
its job and induce the same action choice. However,
a new option arises as it might be possible to allow
the manager to communicate his private information
to the public and thus make the information
available for contracting purposes. Accounting
infonnation is often of this type as accruals are
constructed at the end of a period.
Given the late arrival of this information it cannot
be used for selecting the action. The communicated
infonnation can only be used for control purposes
Vol. 40, No. 3. 2010 International Accounting Policy Forum 291
as the information might be used to induce the
efficient operation of the firm through incentive pay.
The communication of such private information is
constrained as the manager will only communicate
signals that are in the interest of the messenger.
Only the manager knows the specifics of the
information and the communication is impossible
to control directly. Thus there is yet another
possibility for gaming by the manager. One way
to resolve this is to make the owner offer a set of
contracts to the manager. The manager is then
supposed to choose among these. This is a revelation
game and through his choice the manager
reveals his private information. The use of the
information for contracting purposes is limited to
the use which is specified in the chosen contract.
What is more important is that the owner has to
commit to refraining fi-om using the information
otherwise. The communication is controlled by the
other more primitive observable variables such as
cash fiows and by the potential use of the information
for control purposes (Christensen, 1982). The
accruals are used for communicating the private
information of the managers, and reporting incentives
have to be taken into consideration. Other
information is used to control the reporting incentives.
If the information is available to the manager
before the decision process is finished, the information
has the potential of informing and thus
directly influencing the decision. This might also be
the very purpose of hiring a manager in the first
place. There is then a potential for using the
information in the evaluation process as in the
previous case, but in addition to that there is also a
possibility for the manager to use the information in
the decision-making process. The double use of the
private information has an impact on the control
problem as that might be improved or made worse.
In extreme cases, the private information might be
of negative value to the firm. The information fi-om
the manager can be extracted in the same way as
above but more complicated incentive issues have
to be taken into consideration (Christensen, 1981).
Communication of private information is possible
both inside and outside the accounting system.
Communication within the accounting system is
limited to financial information. The initial recording
of a transaction takes place inside the accounting
system. This information is then oñen combined
with the manager's private information fi-om outside
the accounting system to form accruals. The
accounting system handles this combination using
consistency as a controlling device. Depreciation is
a good example of how management's expectation
is entered into the accounting system as an accrual.
The initial recording is historical cost and the
depreciation follows a predetermined plan according
to the expectations of management. During the
lifetime of the investment the managers might learn
more about the profitability of the investment. The
normal accounting treatment will not allow such
information to enter the accounting system. Only
hard evidence is accepted as an excuse for changing
the depreciation plan. Modem times call for fair
value to enter the accounting system. Fair value
accounting constitutes another example of accounting
control and here it is historical cost combined
with market data that forms the accrual.
Management has private information concerning
the market value when considering firm-specific
assets. Market value is not always exogenously
given and users of financial statements have
concems about the completeness of the market
search performed by management. The control
problem is easy to solve when there is a wellfunctioning
market for the asset in question. Then it
is routine to report a market-based value of the
asset. When the market is less well-functioning,
evidence has to be present to defend the accounting
treatment.
The communication might also take place outside
the accounting system and then the communication
is fi"ee of the rules, regulation, and conventions that
govern the accounting system. This information
channel is heavily used by modem corporations,
and security regulation is in place to regulate the
sharing of infonnation among market participants.
The content of the communication is subject to
market control, and the published financial statements
are certainly part of the set of controls.
2.5. Auditing
Auditing is an important part of the controls that
allow private information to be communicated to
the decision-makers. The auditor might have two
functions: that of a quality control and that of an
independent actor who provides credibility to the
report (Kinney, 2000). Given the regulation which
surrounds the auditing profession, the latter task
must be very important. The first task could easily
be carried out by a person who is directly employed
by the firm. The latter task calls for independence
(Antle, 1984).
The auditor usually has a disadvantage compared
to the manager of the firm when it comes to
information about the firm. If reporting incentives
were trivial, the manager's self-reporting of firmspecific
information would clearly dominate any
information that the auditor could provide. It is also
292 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
noteworthy that the auditor only provides an
opinion of the published financial statements.
Thus, he is not producing the information himself
but only verifying the content. Given the problematic
reporting incentives of management, this fiinction
increases the infonnation content of the
published statements. (Christensen and Demski,
2003). A consequence of this finding is that it is
very important that the information contained in the
accounting system can be audited. In that way, audit
ability also becomes a constraint on the accounting
system.
3. Demand for information
S.I. The users of financial statements
The demand for accounting information, even for a
simple firm and only considering the owners (and
potential owners) and the manager, is quite complicated.
The present and potential owners have
investment decisions as well as control decisions.
The demand for infonnation depends upon the
fiiture cash flows, the control problem that is faced
by the organisation, the access of the two parties to
infonnation, whether there is any private information,
and the possible observables to be used in
contracting. The usefiilness of communicated private
information is very sensitive to all of these
factors. Consequently, even at the firm level, the
demand for information and the optimal choice of
accounting infonnation system wiU be very specific
to the firm characteristics. The demand for information
is partly a response to the fiictions in the
markets faced by the firm and the intenelationship
among the available sources of information, the
goal congruence of management, and the constituents
of the firm and the incentives. A minor change
in one information source might have dramatic
consequences for the information content and the
use of accounting accruals. The reporting incentives
are hard to control. Thus there is no universally best
way to manage the reporting of the firm. The choice
must refiect a cost benefit comparison in order to
reach an optimal system (Christensen and Demski,
2003).
The information content of the accounting system
is mainly firm-specific information providing
the investors with input for their investment decisions.
Most of the information contained in the
accounting system is endogenous to the firm but
some pieces of infonnation are the consequence of
the mixing of endogenous and exogenous information.
The prime example of this is fair value
valuation, which includes market infonnation.
Modem finance has taught us that a rational, riskaverse
investor invests in a diversified portfolio of
assets. The Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM)
has infonned us that the main ingredient in the
pricing of a security is the association of the security
and the market portfolio such that the correlation
between the security and the market portfolio, i.e.
the beta, accounts for the pricing of the security
(Beaver, 1998). The investor will demand a risk
premium for the market risk that is associated with
investing in a specific security. The firm-specific
risk will be diversified and the result is that this part
of the firm-specific risk disappears fi-om the equation.
The investor may also want information about
firm-specific risk in order to diversify, particularly if
he has non-diversifiable endowments (e.g. property
investments or skills). Consequently, the investor's
demand for information concems the risk and the
conelation of the firm retum and the market retum.
This is not the type of information which is given
the highest priorify in the accounting system.
On the supply side, the accounting system
contains financial information about the activities
of the firm. The data are initially collected within the
firm as transactions. Later, revaluations and
accounting accruals are added to the system. As a
result, some data are hard data in tJie form of
realised cash flows, and other data are of a softer
nature as the accmals are based upon the expectations
of management, perhaps inspired by exogenous
events like price changes. A general
characteristic of the accounting information is the
stamp which is provided by the auditor of the firm.
The accounting system has the comparative advantage
that it produces firm-specific information
primarily about the finn's financial position.
Thus the accounting information is not in
demand by the general investor who follows the
advice to invest in well diversified portfolios.
Rather, accounting infonnation is usefiil for persons
who are placed (for some reason) in a speculative
position. Some investors look for information about
fixture cash flows to identify when it is optimal to
exchange the investment for cash. Another group of
investors look for stewardship information to
induce efficient operation of the firm. There is not
a generally best accounting system across firms
(Christensen and Demski, 2003). The optimal
infonnation system is unique to each relationship,
and the accounting system has to compromise
among the users and producers. A choice also has to
reflect the preferences of the stakeholders of the
firms and it has to balance the possible uses of the
accounting system. Furthermore, as Arrow's theorem
suggests the non-existence of a social welfare
choice fiinction, the choice must be the result of a
political decision process (Anow, 1951, and
Vol. 40, No. 3. 20\0 International Accounting Policy Forum 293
Demski, 1973). The exposure draft, (FASB/IASB,
2008), acknowledges this dilemma more specifically
than the extant IASB and FASB conceptual
frameworks, as it identifies the capital providers as
the primary users (para. 0B5 to 0B8). Capital
providers' demand for information includes both
the abilify to generate fiiture cash flow and the
abilify to protect and enhance the investments. The
focus on reporting incentives could be stronger.
This is fijrther mixed with a public goods
problem in the sense that once the information is
produced and the cost for that is incurred, the
information is a free good. Consequently, if left
alone, the market would end up with an undersupply
of accounting information. This creates a
lemons problem (Akerlof, 1970) in the market for
the assets of the firm and there is a demand for
regulation of the supply of firm-specific information.
If the signalling behaviour is important the
result might be an oversupply of information.
3.2. Multiple uses of financial information
According to the discussion of the reporting firm,
accounting serves two purposes: decision and
control. Information for decision purposes is information
that enables the decision-maker (an
investor) to estimate the fiiture cash flows for
investment decisions. This means information that
feeds into the net present value calculation.
Different signals lead to different decisions.
Information for control purposes informs the decision-
maker about the 'act' selected by the manager
of the firm. Here the important characteristic is the
ability of the information to provide information
that enables the owner to distinguish the desirable
from the undesirable action. The purpose of this is
then to allow the owner to provide incentives for
selection of the desirable action. The two purposes
are not identical and the rankings of information
systems according to these two purposes do not
necessarily coincide. This means that when faced
with a choice among a set of information systems,
one information system might be preferred for one
purpose and another might be preferred for the other
purpose. This implies that there is not one universally
optimal accounting system independent of the
use of the information (Gjesdal, 1981; Christensen
and Demski, 2003).
One way to proceed is to consider several
accounting systems - one for each purpose or user
group. Generically that could be one for control
purposes and one for decision purposes serving the
stockholders of the firm. In this way, the accounting
system could overcome the incentive issues raised
previously as management will only communicate
information which is in its own best interest for
control purposes. Separating the two sets of reports
will remove this conflict. Unfortunately this is not a
viable option. Management will only communicate
everything if the users are able to and will commit
not to use the information too aggressively. Given
the separation of management and stockholders, it
is hardly possible for the owners to commit to such a
policy. Bad news in the decision information
domain will at some point spill over to bad news
in the control domain and thus the incentives for
complete and truthfiil communication in the decision
domain break down. Therefore, we cannot
expect that a separation of the user groups and their
reports will lead to an accounting system for
decision-making which is free from the bias introduced
by the incentives of management.
4. The properties of accounting information
4.1. The qualitative characteristics of financial
statements
The qualitative characteristics of the conceptual
framework are the attributes which make the
information usefiil to users according to the
conceptual frameworks of the IASB (IASC, 1989)
and FASB (FASB, 1980a, 1980b, 1984, 1985). This
is the important link between the information source
and the users. The qualitative characteristics then
fiinction as a proxy for the users. The details of the
decision problem are replaced by the qualitative
characteristics. As noted earlier, the origin of the
qualitative characteristics is related to the decision
orientation of accounting and was stated in the
ASOBAT report (AAA, 1966). These qualitative
characteristics certainly describe the attribute for a
useful information system when it is used for
decision-making purposes in a one-person world.
The inherent multi-person nature of most accounting
issues is ignored. The question to be analysed
here is whether the qualitative characteristics can
replace the users when the regulators are deciding
upon accounting standards.
Focus first on the pair 'relevance' and 'reliability'
as these attributes have hitherto been identified as
the most important ones (although 'reliability' is
replaced by 'faithfiil representation' in FASB/IASB,
2008). The IASB conceptual framework (IASC,
1989: para. 45) calls for a balancing between
qualitative characteristics but offers little assistance
beyond a reference to 'professional judgement'. In
the wording of the Exposure Draft (FASB/IASB,
2008), 'Enhancing qualitative characteristics
improve the usefulness of financial information
and should be maximised to the extent possible'
(para. QC 25). In order to analyse this balance.
294 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
briefly consider the model of Feltham and Xie
(1994). They consider a multi-task agency model.
The manager faces a two-dimensional task and is
supposed to select an action pair a = (a^, 02). The
owner wants to maximise expected profit U = biai +
02^2- The accountant has to choose between two
different information systems. The first will report a
profit of;?! = ¿la, + ¿202 + ei and the second will
report a different profit ofp2 = Cjûi + C2a2. The first
information system weighs the two actions according
to the objective function of the firm but has
noise as well. The second has no noise but gives a
biased profit compared to the objective ofthe firm.
Thus the first information system scores high on
relevance and low on reliability. The second is very
reliable but less relevant. Using the two infonnation
systems for contracting purposes illustrates the
consequences of a second best world. Using the first
profit measure leads to a deficiency. Providing
incentives to work imposes a non-trivial risk upon
the manager and consequently he requires a risk
premium in his pay for performance contract. The
second information system leads to a decision from
the manager which is not aligned with the first best
choice as the mix ofthe two actions is skewed. This
is also inefficient. Consequently, there will be
different costs associated with the two infonnation
systems. The first will include a risk premium and
the second will refiect the unbalanced weighted
decision. Now perform a comparative static analysis.
If b is small (compared to ci) the second
information system will be optimal. If b is large
(compared to ^i) the first information system will be
optimal. The information systems including the
relevance or reliability characteristics are not
changed,' yet the optimal information system
changes as a consequence of the difference in the
underlying decision problem. The optimal choice is
not accurately described by the pair relevance and
reliability. Wagenhofer (2009) makes a similar
point.
To take the analysis one step fiarther, the concept
of faithful representation or neutrality is considered.
Faithful representation means that the transactions
and other events should be represented in the
financial statements in a way it purports to be. This
takes away any consideration of managerial incentives
to control the information system. Yet it is
widely acknowledged and documented that there is
a phenomenon called eamings management and
that this takes on many forms. This has been
' i t is suggested that reliability is replaced by faithful
representation in FASB (2008). This replacement does not
change the argument as the interpretations of reliability and
faithful representation are identical in the proposed setting.
documented in many and very different ways (Dye,
2002; Nelson et al., 2002; Demski, 1998). The next
level of eamings management has led to the
emergence of something that might be labelled
designer transactions, which stands for transactions
that just satisfy a set of conditions to qualify for
being accounted for in a specific way. The Enron
case was a huge system of such designer transactions.
The point is that the focus on qualitative
characteristics skips over the finer details of the
decision problem and in this case over the reaction
of those making the reporting system once a
regulation is in place. They might design transactions
to circumvent the regulation. The regulators
must consider the incentives of the information
producers to maximise the result of the regulation
effort. Furthermore, this might lead to optimality of
non-neutral standards and non-neutral accounts as
suggested by Dye (2002) and Christensen and
Demski (2007).
The qualitative characteristics work as a way of
simplifying the decision problem faced by the
regulators as the finer details of the accounting
decision problem including preferences, decision
problems and information environment are simplified
into only viewing the qualitative characteristics
of accounting infonnation. This appears to be too
simplistic as it blinds the regulators to incentives
that are inherent in the system producing accounting
information and to the more delicate trade-offs that
the regulators (and information producers) are
facing.
4.2. The fundamental properties of financial
statements
In very general terms, the purpose of financial
statements is to provide information for the constituents
of the firm. This is a very broad purpose,
yet financial statements have some very fundamental
properties which will remain no matter the
regulation. Some of these will be discussed in the
six points below. First, the optimal reporting for the
firm is unique to the specifics of the firm. Second,
the general purpose of accounting information is
usually cast in the wording of decision information
and stewardship information. The bias introduced
by the stewardship use of accounting information
will always remain. Third, the accounting information
specialises in firm-specific information, and
mainly investors holding a speculative position
benefit from financial reporting. Fourth, the
accounting information is inherently late compared
to other information sources. Fifth, the accounting
system does not exist in a vacuum. Other information
sources are present and the purpose of the
Vol. 40, No. 3. 2010 Intemational Accounting Policy Forum 295
accounting system cannot be analysed without
considering the existence of other infonnation
sources. Sixth, the financial statements are audited
by an independent auditor. This implies that
accounting data are hard to manipulate.
Eventually a synthesis of these points will lead to
the identification of the role of the conceptual
framework.
Following the earlier discussion of the reporting
firm, the main content in financial statements is
financial infonnation about the firm. This follows
from the historical development and it also reflects
the comparative advantage of financial reporting.
Furthennore, it was concluded that the optimal
information system, which balances cost and benefits
of the information system, is highly specific to
the details of the specific reporting situation. This
includes the decision problems faced, the information
present, and the distribution of this information
among involved parties. There is no universally
optimal infonnation system independent of the
specifics of the reporting situation.
Furthennore, it is well established that the
rankings of infonnation systems for decision purposes
and stewardship purposes are not aligned
(Gjesdal, 1981). As argued earlier, it follows from
the institutional setting that it is impossible to have
two different financial reporting systems - one for
stewardship purposes and one for decision purposes.
It is impossible for the users to commit to not
using the decision-relevant infonnation for stewardship
purposes as the use of the information
system is decoupled from the production.
Consequently, the situation-specific optimal
accounting system will balance the pros and cons
of the information system for the different purposes.
This suggests that there is always a bias in the
accruals which is related to the stewardship use of
the infonnation.
Another point is how the accounting system best
supplements the other, perhaps more timely, information
sources that are found in the infonnation
society. The famous Ball and Brown (1968)
diagram suggests financial accounting indeed provides
information which is used by the market
participants to value the securities in the market.
Unfortunately, the diagram also suggests that only a
small fraction (8% according to Lev, 1989) of the
total infonnation released to the market stems from
the published financial statements. The market
reacts to all kinds of infonnation and this information
is clearly timelier than accounting infonnation.
Yet most infonnation sources are not regulated.
Accounting infonnation is heavily regulated and
has an important effect on other information
sources. The financial report has a potential for
controlling the infonnation content in other perhaps
more timely information sources.
The conceptual framework implicitly assumes
that financial statements should carry all relevant
information and thus it disregards the existence of
other information sources. This view does not allow
for a specialisation of the different types of
infonnation sources. The accounting system constructed
in one way might be a better supplement to
existing infonnation sources than another accounting
system that is supposed to stand on its own. The
big question remains as to who is best able to
aggregate the financial information with other
sources of infonnation which are available to the
market participant. It appears to be too naive to
assume or conclude that this aggregation is best
performed by the accountants. The famous Roll
(1984) paper suggests that this should be taken
seriously. Who would, at the outset, have expected
the financial markets to outperform a set of
meteorologists when it comes to forecasting weather
in a small region of Central Florida? The
market mechanism is an extremely strong information
aggregator and it might, despite the fact that
each of the market participants only has very noisy
information compared to the firm, be very efficient
at performing such an aggregation
The final observation is that financial statements
are unique in the sense that they are audited. That is,
the private infonnation of the firm is verified by an
independent auditor before being entered into the
financial statements. Consequently, only information
that passes this filter is included (Kinney,
2000). This implies that financial statements are
hard to manipulate and produce hard infonnation
that is useftil in repairing inefficiencies in markets.
Where do these six observations lead? First of all,
financial statements are not particularly suited to
serve the diversified investor. Mainly to investors
holding speculative positions will the financial
statements be of value. Next, is the balancing of
information to be included in and excluded from the
financial statements? The first observation is that
this is an empirical question as it is highly
contingent upon the situation whether the accountant
or the market is best at aggregating information.
Routinely, the accounting system steps away from
including investment in the ftiture into the assets
because the benefits are uncertain both with regard
to timing and amount. The market has no problem
in including such information into the valuation of
securities. The second observation is that accounting
information is inherently late by construction.
Events have to take place and the entry into the
296 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
published statements has to be verified by an
auditor. Numerous sources of information step in
and fill the gap. This is evidenced by Ball and
Brown's (1968) diagram and Beaver (1998).
This leads to the following question: why
regulate accounting information when most of the
information action is going on in the non-regulated
regime of other information sources? These sources
are perhaps regulated with respect to timing due to
securities regulation but not with respect to content.
One possible answer to that question is that the
regulated accounting information serves as the
information source which 'controls' the other
information sources. Then all free voluntary information
disclosures are at the time of financial
reporting compared to the published financial
statements. If they are consistent it is viewed as
good news, whereas inconsistency is regarded as
bad news. The information content of the voluntary
disclosure is a fiinction of the control that is built
into the accounting system. The financial statements
serve an important role in controlling such information.
5. Accounting regulation
5.1. The purpose of a conceptual framework
Before going into the specifics of the present and
proposed conceptual framework it might be useful
to consider the stated purpose and scope of the
conceptual framework. The purpose of the present
IASB conceptual fi-amework is to assist the Board in
developing future accounting standards, to assist
the Board in promoting harmonisation of regulations
and accounting standards, to assist national
standard-setters, to assist auditors in formulating
opinions, and to assist users (IASC, 1989). The
FASB states a similar purpose (FASB, 1980b).
Thus, the purpose is twofold. One is to help the
standard-setter to develop future standards, and the
other is to help those producing and using the
financial statements. A framework could be
regarded as a constitution defining the general
principles for the development of accounting
standards in the regulatory domain and for the
infonnation content of financial statements in the
users' domain. To fulfil this purpose a framework
should be invariant over a long period and formulate
the general rules which constitute the core of
financial reporting.
As already indicated, the IASB and the FASB are
jointly participating in a project that is intended to
lead to a new conceptual framework which unites
the two fi-ameworks of the two institutions. This
work is in progress and many preliminary working
papers have been released for comment. In the
exposure drañ of the joint Conceptual Framework
(FASB/IASB, 2008) the purpose is reformulated as
establishing concepts that underlie financial reporting.
The framework is thought of as a coherent set of
concepts that fiows from an objective. Many
questions are being asked and not many have an
immediate answer.
5.2. Coordination of the financial statements
The research activities of the universities serve the
implicit regulation of accounting. Most of the ideas
which form the basis for our thinking of accounting
issues stem from the research community. The
notable contribution of Paton and Littleton (1940)
on corporate accounting standards provides a deep
insight into the fundamental and problematic issues
of income measurement. Also the American
Accounting Association's Committees on
Accounting Reporting have had some infiuence,
most notably the ASOBAT (AAA, 1966) report.
The research industry is not well coordinated.
Consequently, a set of definitions of the elements of
financial statements is part of the conceptual
fi-amework. The elements are the assets, the liabilities,
the equity, the income, and the expenses. The
framework also provides definitions of recognition
rules related to the basic elements. Finally, the
general rules of accounting measurement are
included in the conceptual framework. Taken
together, the definition of elements of financial
statements is thought to govern the inclusion and
exclusion of information in the financial statements.
Analysing the demand for accounting information
for a specific entity leads to a specific optimal
information structure. The accounting system has to
be finely tuned to the specifics of the organisation
and its environment. The flexibility of the accounting
system is a key to its success as an information
system. Within the general framework of accrual
accounting there is room for many variations. This
allows feeding the expectations of management into
the accounting information in a controlled way. Too
much regulation would destroy this flexibility and
leave the accounting system useless (Christensen
and Demski, 2003).
The optimal accounting information system will
fill the gap lefi between the private and public
infonnation to induce optimal decision-making in
the most general sense. Provided there is a welldefined
social preference relationship this information
will possibly be unique except for the representation
or the scaling of the information system.
Sending a message fi-om one individual to another
might take on many equivalent forms, e.g. using
different languages. The important function of
Vol. 40, No. 3. 20\0 International Accounting Policy Forum 297
financial statements as an infonnation source is that
the users are able to invert the mapping that
produces the information in the first place such
that the user leams the primitive underlying state
realisation or event (set of events) (Antle and
Demski, 1989; Demski and Sappington, 1990).
As the world contains many firms and many
decision-makers, there is a demand for coordination
of the scaling or representation of the infonnation.
This would serve the purpose of coordination
among different users of the information such that
the infonnation might be understood by a broader
audience and not coded for a specific user. In the
framework this is equivalent to tiie set of definitions
and the set of eiements which constitute the
financial statements. No doubt this demand for
coordination is real. The demand could be satisfied
in the financial statements as a description of the
applied accounting methods. The textbooks or
professors are other candidates for taking care of
this coordination. Given the anarchistic and innovative
nature of both, this is probably not a good place
to do the coordination. National regulation will not
do the job either, given the open society.
Consequently, this job is best served by the
intemational accounting regulation.
As noted previously, the current view is that
financial statements provide financial information
about the firm. The format of the information
system is defined as accmal accounting and
universally agreed upon. Pointing this out belongs
to a long-term valid conceptual fi-amework. The
specific definitions of what constitutes the elements
of the subsection of the financial statements are
subject to change as part of an evolution and might
be better placed in the standards.
5.3. A conceptual framework
There is certainly a demand for accounting regulation
as a market failure can be observed in the
market for information supply. Those who possess
the information might have poor incentives to
disclose such information and the market is also
haunted by a lemons problem as suggested by
Akerlof (1970). The literature on the demand for
regulation of financial statements is vast and a
recent summary of the arguments is given by
Bushman and Landsman (2010).
Now to the initial question of how do conceptual
fi-ameworks contribute to the qualify of corporate
reporting regulation? The conceptual fi-amework
can be viewed as the constitution (statement of
fundamental laws and principles) that keeps control
over the process of accounting regulation. A
constitution should have long-term validify and it
should not be changed in response to small changes
in the workings of sociefy. This calls for a rather
robust wording of the conceptual fi-amework.
However, this is not the way the present conceptual
framework is set up. It is far too detailed and might
consequently fail in its purpose, as observed by the
AAA committee on Financial Reporting (AAA,
2009). I share their view.
A conceptual fi-amework should fiinction as a
constitution to remind the regulators of the overall
goal of financial reporting such that the details of
individual standards are kept in line with that.
Therefore a conceptual fi-amework should contain
that goal. As found earlier there is not unanimify
among stakeholders on this issue and it is part of a
political process. Thus it is impossible to define
what is meant by qualify of corporate reporting
objectively and often we are reducing this question
to one of measuring the cost and benefits of
regulation as in Schipper (2010). The regulators
are supposed to balance the pros and cons of
introducing or revising a standard. The overall goal
is to find a socially optimal level of disclosure of
firm-specific financial information which leads to
well fiinctioning capital markets and to efficient
firms. Rather than providing a set of qualitative
characteristics which does not guide the regulatory
process, as noted earlier, it would be more usefial to
state the perceived comparative advantages and the
perceived limitations of financial statements.
One of the advantages of the accounting system
is that it is audited, which makes the information
hard to manipulate. This is important given the role
accounting plays in reporting otherwise undisclosed
information and in controlling other sources of
infonnation. It might also flag that some pieces of
information are hard evidence, whereas other pieces
are softer, such as accruals. The latter are reported
by management but have an accounting stamp as
the procedure for producing them lends itself to
auditing. The usefiiiness of the pieces of accounting
information depends critically upon the hardness of
the data.
The limitations include the potential bias of
financial statements. The word bias can be interpreted
in two ways. One meaning implies that the
statements do not represent the expected value of
the asset, i.e. the reported value is not equal to the
mean. It is admittedly a nice property that a
measurement is fi-ee fi-om bias, but any deviation
fi-om this norm does not constitute a major problem
as that is easily resolved once the source of the bias
is known. The troublesome part is the bias
introduced by an involved parfy. Identifying and
resolving this fype of bias could point to the
298 ACCOUNTING AND BUSINESS RESEARCH
importance of the incentives of management for the
preparation and interpretation of financial statements.
This would put these incentives in a central
role when it comes to the development of new
standards and when it comes to interpreting the
financial statements of firms. Along these lines, the
AAA committee has developed a few ground rules
for a conceptual framework (AAA, 2009). The
fiiture development of the standards might benefit
from allowing competition among standards and
allowing firms to decide which set of standards they
want to satisfy (Dye and Sunder, 2001).
6. Summary and conclusions
The conceptual framework has been with us for a
long time and the regulation of accounting even
longer. Much regulation has been a consequence of
observed business failures (Clikeman, 2009). The
globalisation of business has led to a call for
harmonisation of accounting standards around the
globe and as a result the FASB and IASB have
joined forc'es to make one set of accounting
standards. One of their joint projects is a common
conceptual framework ^ASB/IASB, 2006, 2008).
Consequently, the present interest in the development
of a new framework is seen.
In this paper I have reviewed the demand for a
conceptual framework from an information economics
perspective. This has been a broad analysis.
The point of departure was supposed to be the
consequences for the quality of financial reporting
of a conceptual framework. This is a very difficult
question as the notion of quality is very hard to
describe in the first place and secondly because the
roles of allocation between a conceptual framework,
the actual accounting regulation, and the
information content in financial statements are not
predetermined. Therefore, I have taken the path of
analysing the role and content of a conceptual
framework as a set of ground rules that is usefiil in
the regulation of financial reporting.
The focal point of a conceptual framework must
be the comparative advantage of accounting.
Accounting is an information source which is
always produced late in a decision process. That
stems from the fact that a main characteristic of
accounting information is that accounting data: (1)
are based upon the financial relationship of the firm
with outside parties and upon formal recognition
rules; (2) are subject to auditing; (3) acknowledge
the role of other, perhaps more timely, information
sources; (4) aggregate and allocate information over
time and units; and (5) are hard to manipulate. It is
an important role for the conceptual framework to
help the accounting system in maintaining the
comparative advantage.
References
AAA (1966). A Statement of Basic Accounting Theory.
(ASOBAT). American Accounting Association.
AAA (2009). Alternative Conceptual Frameworks for
Financial Reporting. American Accounting Association.
Akerlof, G. (1970). 'The market for "lemons": quality,
uncertainty, and the market mechanism'. Quarterly Journal
of Economics, 84(3): 488-500.
Antle, R. (1984). 'Auditor independence'. Journal of
Accounting Research, 22(1): 1-20.
Antle, R. and Demski, J. (1988). 'The controllability
principle in responsibility accounting'. The Accounting
Review, 63(4): 700-718.
Antle, R. and Demski, J. (1989). 'Revenue recognition'.
Contemporary Accounting Research, 5(2): 423-451.
Arrow, K. (1951). Social Choice and Individual Values. New
Haven, CT: Yale University Press.
Ball, R. and Brown, P. (1968). 'An empirical evaluation of
accounting income numbers'. Reprinted in Journal of
Accounting Research, (1989) 27: 202-217.
Beaver, W. (1998). Financial Reporting: An Accounting
Revolution. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall.
Beaver, W. and Demski, J. (1979). 'The nature of income
measurement'. The Accounting Review, 54(1): 38-46.
Bromwich, M., Macve, R. and Sunder, S. (2009). 'Hicksian
income in the conceptual framework'. Unpublished manuscript,
London School of Economics (LSE).
Burgstahler, D. and Dichev, I. (1997). 'Earnings management
to avoid earnings decreases and losses'. Journal of
Accounting & Economics, 24(1): 99-126.
Bushman, R. and Landsman, W.R. (2010). 'The pros and
cons of regulating corporate reporting: a critical review of
the arguments'. Accounting and Business Research, 40(3)
(Special Issue): 259-273.
Christensen, J. (1981). 'Communication in agencies'. Bell
Journal of Economics, 12(2): 661-674.
Christensen, J. (1982). 'The determination of performance
standards and participation. Journal of Accounting
Research, 20(2): 589-603.
Christensen, J. and Demski, J. (2003). Accounting Theory.
An Information Content Perspective. New York, NY:
McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Christensen, J. and Demski, J. (2007). 'Anticipatory reporting
standards'. Accounting Horizons 21(4): 351-370.
Christensen, J. and Frimor, H. (2007). 'Fair value, accounting
aggregation and multiple sources of information'. In R.
Antle, P.J. Liang and F. Gjesdal (eds.). Essays on
Accounting Theory in Honour of Joel S. Demski, pp. 1-
15. Kluwer.
Clikeman, P.M. (2009). Called to Account. Fourteen
Financial Frauds that Shaped the American Accounting
Profession. Routledge.
Demski, J. (1973). 'The general impossibility of normative
accounting standards'. The Accounting Review, 48(4): 718-
723.
Demski, J. (1998). 'Performance measure manipulation'.
Contemporary Accounting Research, 15(3): 261-285.
Demski, J. and Sappington, D. (1990). 'Fully revealing
income measurement'. The Accounting Review, 6(2)- 363-
383.
Dye, R.A. (2002). 'Classifications manipulation and Nash
Vol. 40, No. 3. 2010 International Accounting Policy Forum 299
accounting standards'. Journal of Accounting Research,
40(4): 1125-1162.
Dye, R.A. and Sunder, S. (2001). 'Why not allow FASB atid
IASB standards to compete in the U.S.?'. Accounting
Horizons, 15(3): 257-271.
FASB (1978). Concepts Statement No. 1: Objectives of
Financial Reporting by Business Enterprises. Financial
Accounting Standards Board.
FASB (1980a). Concepts Statement No. 2: Qualitative
Characteristics of Accounting Information. Financial
Accounting Standards Board.
FASB (1980b). Concepts Statement No. 4: Objectives of
Financial Reporting by Nonbusiness Organizations.
Financial Accounting Standards Board.
FASB (1984). Concepts Statement No. 5: Recognition and
Measurement in Financial Statements of Business
Enterprises. Financial Accounting Standards Board.
FASB (1985). Concepts Statement No. 6: Elements of
Financial Statements. Financial Accounting Standards
Board.
FASB/IASB (2006). Preliminary Views on an Improved
Conceptual Framework for Financial Reporting: The
Objective of Financial Reporting and Qualitative
Characteristics of Decision-useful Financial Reporting
Information. Issued for comment by the Financial
Accounting Standards Board and by the International
Accounting Standards Board.
FASB/IASB (2008). Conceptual Framework for Financial
Reporting: The Objective of Financial Reporting and
Qualitative Characteristics and Constraints of Decision-
Useful Financial Reporting Information. Exposure Draft.
Issued by the Financial Accounting Standards Board and
by the International Accounting Standards Board.
Feltham, G. and Ohlson, J. (1995). 'Valuation and clean
surplus accounting for operating and financial activities'.
Contemporary Accounting Research 11(2): 689-731.
Feltham, G. and Xie, J. (1994). 'Performance measure
congruity and diversity in multi-task principal-agent relations'.
The Accounting Review, 69(3): 429-453.
Gjesdal, F. ( 1981 ). 'Accounting for stewardship'. Journal of
Accounting Research, 19(1): 208-231.
Graham, J.R., Harvey, C.R. and Rajgopal, S. (2005). 'The
economic implications of corporate financial reporting'.
Journal of Accounting & Economics, 40(1-3): 3-73.
Hicks, J. (1946). Value and Capital. Oxford: Clarendon
Press.
Holmstrom, B. (1979). 'Moral hazard and observability'.
Bell Journal of Economics, 10(1): 74-91.
Homgren, C, Foster, G. and Datar, S. (2003). Cost
Accounting: A Managerial Emphasis. New Jersey, NJ:
Prentice-Hall.
IASC (1989). Framework for the Preparation and
Presentation of Financial Statements. Published by the
International Accounting Standards Committee Board
(IASC Board) in July 1989 and adopted by the
International Accounting standards Board (IASB) in
April 2001. Currently available in the annual volume of
IFRS published by the IASB.
Kinney, W. (2000). Information Quality Assurance and
Internal Control for Management Decision Making. New
York, NY: McGraw-Hill.
Lev, B. (1989). 'On the usefulness of eamings and eamings
research: lessons and directions fi-om two decades of
empirical Kitarçh'. Journal of Accounting Research, 27(3)
Supplement: 153-192.
Nelson, M.W., Elliot, J.A. and Tarpley, R.L. (2002).
'Evidence fi-om auditors about managers' and auditors'
eamings management decisions'. The Accounting Review,
77(4) Supplement: 175-202.
Paton, W. and Littleton, A. (1940). An Introduction to
Corporate Accounting Standards. American Accounting
Association.
Peasnell, K.V. (1982). 'Some formal connections between
economic values and yields and accounting numbers'.
Journal of Business Finance & Accounting, 9(3): 361-
381.
Roll, R. (1984). 'Orange juice and weather'. American
Economic Review, 74(5): 861-880.
Schipper, K. (2010). 'How can we measure the cost and
benefits of changes in financial reporting standards?'.
Accounting and Business Research, 40(3) (Special Issue):
309-327.
Sunder, S. (1997). Theory of Accounting and Control.
Cincinnati, OH: South-Westem Publishing.
Wagenhofer, A. (2009). 'Global accounting standards:
reality and ambitions'. Accounting Research Journal,
22(1): 68-80.
Copyright of Accounting & Business Research is the property of Croner.CCH Group Limited and its content
may not be copied or emailed to multiple sites or posted to a listserv without the copyright holder's express
written permission. However, users may print, download, or email articles for individual use.